The Politics of Infrastructure: Balancing User Fees and Value Capture

BY RICK RYBECK*
Just Economics, LLC

On November 23rd, “60 Minutes” broadcast an episode about crumbling infrastructure in the United States. According to the show, most politicians, corporations, business interest groups and labor unions recognize the importance of infrastructure in maintaining our economic competitiveness, both at home and abroad. But, nobody can agree about how to raise the funds to maintain and repair roads, runways, ports, railroads, etc.

There are several reasons for this. FIRST, when infrastructure works well, it is almost invisible and people take it for granted. You turn on the faucet and water comes out. You get in your car and then arrive at your destination. We hardly think about the treatment facilities, pipes and valves that supply our water. Neither do we think about the pavement, the traffic signals, the street lights, the pavement markings and all of the other street-related facilities and services that make our car trips possible – unless they don’t work.

SECOND, in many cases we have divorced payment for infrastructure from its consumption. When we pay our income and sales taxes, we don’t have a clear understanding about how the money is spent – on infrastructure or anything else. And because it often appears to be free to use streets and highways, we drive and park in congested places at congested times more than we would if we had to pay the true costs of doing so.

THIRD, when infrastructure is well-designed and well-implemented, it often inflates the price of well-served land. So after paying taxes for highways or transit, if we want to get the most value out of them, we want to have our homes or businesses near a highway interchange or a transit station. But the price of land near these facilities has increased as a result of that new infrastructure. So now we must pay a landowner a premium rent or price to have access to the land that our taxes made more valuable in the first place.

This compels many of us to locate our homes and businesses at cheaper, but more remote sites where we don’t have access to the infrastructure that we have paid for. And when enough of us locate at these remote locations, infrastructure is extended there (at great expense) only to have the cycle start again and have development pushed even farther away. Thus the infrastructure we create to facilitate development pushes development away and is partly responsible for sprawl. Not only does sprawl harm the environment, but its duplication of infrastructure facilities and services wastes our tax dollars and cripples our governmental budgets.

Often we hear politicians say, “We are funding this infrastructure to facilitate development and create jobs.” But then, high land prices make development difficult. While most families and businesses must relocate to cheaper and less productive locations, big developers go to politicians looking for land write-downs, property tax abatements or other subsidies. Then we hear the politicians say, “We are subsidizing this development because, without this subsidy, there would be no jobs and no new tax revenues whatsoever.” Isn’t job-creation the reason we paid for the infrastructure initially? Yet now it appears that we don’t get those jobs unless we pay an additional subsidy to developers. Paying twice for infrastructure and paying twice to foster jobs does not make the public happy or enthusiastic about paying for more.

FOURTH, while politicians love ribbon-cutting ceremonies for new infrastructure, they don’t get public acclaim when they appropriate funds for infrastructure repair or maintenance. But keeping taxes low is always going to be a political winner.

Fortunately, there are ways to address these issues.

First, an increased reliance on user fees can help reconnect consumers with what they are consuming. For example, most of us pay for water and sewer services through a per-gallon charge on the water that we consume or flush. When we have a leaky faucet, we don’t just see water going down the drain. We see our money going down the drain and this motivates us to fix the leak and to conserve water generally. Of course, we could pay for water and sewer services out of a sales tax. But would we be as motivated to fix a leak? Would we make an additional and unnecessary purchase to provide sales tax revenue to compensate the water authority for the water we are wasting? Probably not.

In the transportation arena, mileage-based user fees, adjusted for congestion, would encourage some discretionary trips to move out of the peak period and into the off-peak. Performance-based parking fees (as suggested by Professor Donald Shoup) would also go a long way toward improving transportation behavior. And mileage-based roadway charges would encourage families and businesses to locate closer to the activities that they engage in on a daily basis. This could help curtail sprawl by motivating infill development. This would make walking, cycling, car-sharing, carpooling and transit more convenient. Thus, properly designed user fees could encourage more efficient land use patterns that would be beneficial to the environment and our pocket books while wasting less of our time in traffic jams.

Some people think that mileage-based user fees adjusted for congestion are too complicated and too invasive of our privacy. Yet, the Washington, DC Metrorail system charges fares that vary by both distance and time-of-day. This encourages some riders to make discretionary trips at off-peak times. This makes the entire system more efficient. Hundreds of thousands of trips are made each day on Metrorail. So this is not just abstract theory. This is reality. (Washington, DC, San Francisco and several other cities are also implementing performance-based parking pricing.)

Second, we need to balance user fees with more reliance on “value capture.” Many public goods and services inflate the value of well-served sites. Today, the lion’s share of this value ends up as a windfall to the landowners who are lucky enough (or shrewd enough) to own the best-served sites. Let’s return to the water and sewer example. The owner of a vacant lot isn’t drinking or flushing any water at that site. Should the owner pay anything to the water and sewer authority?

Imagine a thriving town with unmet demand for housing and business space. There are two vacant lots of the same size. They have the same zoning and equally convenient access to the downtown and all of the public and private amenities except that one lot has water and sewer pipes at the property’s edge and the other does not have water and sewer pipes within a half mile of the property. Which property is more valuable? The property with water and sewer pipes at the property boundary is more valuable. But not because of anything that the owner did. That lot is more valuable because the water and sewer authority built (and maintains) those pipes at the property’s edge. Value capture consists of techniques to return that publicly-created land value to the public entity that created it.

A good example of the balance between user fees and value capture was created in the 1890s. At that time, the Chevy Chase Land Company (CCLC) bought about 1,700 acres of land on both sides of the border between Washington, DC and Maryland. This land, mostly farms and woodland, was very cheap because it did not have good access to the downtown where the jobs and shops were located. CCLC, at its own expense, built a streetcar line down Connecticut Avenue connecting its landholdings with the downtown. They charged people a few pennies to ride it.

CCLC did not recoup their costs through the farebox. Was this charity or altruism on their part? Absolutely not. CCLC recouped its costs (and more) through the higher prices that they charged for home lots and business lots that were now accessible to the downtown via convenient and affordable transit. It is important to note that if CCLC had attempted to recoup all of its costs through the farebox, the fares would have been so high that nobody would have ridden it. Thus, if CCLC had attempted to recoup costs only through fares, both the streetcar and the land development projects would have failed.

Today, some communities are using value capture to transform their property tax into an infrastructure access fee by reducing the tax rate on privately-created building values and increasing the tax rate on publicly-created land values. The lower tax on buildings makes them cheaper to construct, improve and maintain. This is good for residents and businesses alike.

Surprisingly, the higher tax on land helps keep land prices more affordable. (It reduces the profit from land speculation, thereby reducing the speculative demand for land.) Returning infrastructure-created land values to the public helps make infrastructure financially self-sustaining (at least to a greater degree than today) and thereby reduces the need for other taxes and subsidies. It also creates some fairness in infrastructure funding because landowners who benefit from infrastructure end up paying in proportion to the benefits that they receive.

Additionally, value capture motivates the development of high-value locations. These tends to be infill sites near existing urban infrastructure amenities like transit and parks – and this is exactly where we want development to occur. And the more we develop infill sites, the less demand will exist for premature development of remote areas that are more appropriate for agriculture, conservation and recreation. As mentioned above, curtailing sprawl is good for the environment, it boosts productivity, and it reduces the extensiveness (and expensiveness) of the infrastructure required to satisfy homes and businesses, thereby reducing tax burdens.

There is no single answer about how to fund the infrastructure work that needs to be done. More widespread application of user fees (like congestion-pricing for roads and parking and storm-water runoff fees) are an important part of the equation. And “value capture” is almost always overlooked in spite of its potential to provide significant, fair and comprehensible funding for essential infrastructure investments. Finally, the solution for many transportation problems has little to do with transportation and more to do with land use. A properly designed and balanced system of user fees and value capture can reduce sprawl and promote more efficient land use that is beneficial for the environment, our economy and our public and private pocket books.

For more information on some of these ideas, see “Funding Infrastructure for Growth, Sustainability and Equity,” a report prepared for the DC Tax Revision Commission.

* Rick Rybeck is the director of Just Economics, LLC, a firm that helps communities harmonize economic incentives with public policy objectives for job creation, affordable housing, transportation efficiencies and sustainable development.

The views and opinions expressed in this article are those of the author and do not necessarily reflect the official policy or position of The Eno Center for Transportation.

Search Eno Transportation Weekly

Latest Issues

Happening on the Hill